by: Yong SK/

On July 11, 2011, the two major Public Transport Operators (PTOs), SBS Transit and SMRT, submitted their proposals to the Public Transport Council (PTC) to raise fares, raising eyebrows among Singaporeans who have been unhappy with the service of the PTOs over the years. The Workers’ Party then reiterated a call that was made in the 2006 and 2011 polls to nationalise the PTOs to oversee and run major transport services.

However, Singapore’s Transport Minister, Mr. Lui Tuck Yew, has come forward to defend the current transport arrangement and rejected the idea of nationalizing the PTOs. Mr. Lui has mentioned that “the Workers’ Party proposal for the public transport system to be nationalised has serious downsides, chief amongst which commuters and taxpayers, including those who do not take public transport, are likely to end up paying more, and possibly, for a poorer level of service over time”.

“Paying more …for a poorer level of service over time”

While this is Mr Lui’s gloomy prognosis of a transport system with a nationalised operator, I hasten to point out that EVEN in the current situation, with a privatised operator (SMRT), we commuters are already facing a similar situation – massive overcrowding, more frequent breakdowns, poor management during breakdowns and security lapses, and yet, constant increase in transport fares. Also, for those who do not use public transport, they are also paying, not in pecuniary terms, but the cost of traffic congestion which is due to more cars on the road, and which in turn and in part to people preferring to drive because of dissatisfaction with public transport services.

Mr. Lui has also mentioned that a nationalised public transport operator that depends on government funding and which operates on a cost recovery basis would have little incentive to keep costs down. Cost increases will be passed on to commuters. We are not given evidence of how these PTOs have “kept costs down”. However, if what Mr. Lui said is true, why would a company that has successfully managed (or even reduced) its costs and is making decent profits (ref SMRT’s annual reports) over the years need to constantly apply for increment in fares?

The Privatised PTOs and Performance
Another important issue pointed out by Mr. Lui is that over time, a nationalised PTO will lead to higher costs for the same level of service, which means commuters pay higher, and not lower fares and hence, not only would people have to pay more but nationalising the operators could result in a stagnation of service quality or efficiency over time. Mr. Lui’s argument here seems somewhat simplistic.

Firstly, what Mr. Lui has stated is an exact reflection of what commuters are currently facing. Since the SMRT started operating, Singapore commuters have been paying higher fares over time with somewhat same level of service. The improvement in frequency of trains does not commensurate with the rapid increase in population due to influx of non-Singaporeans. Although much evidence on successful privatization and deregulation of common state-owned enterprises are available, our current private transport operators have displayed stagnation of service quality with constant increment in fares.

Hence, even with private PTOs, commuters in Singapore are facing similar problems in a nationalised PTO. In terms of efficiency, it depends on which definition of efficiency you are referring to, in which we shall discuss in the next section.

Most people who are well-trained in economics will agree with Mr. Lui that the profit incentive of commercial enterprises will spur privately-run PTOs’ efficiency and productivity improvements, and it is the main reason many cities around the world have use commercial enterprises to provide public transport services. In economics, there are two main types of efficiencies: allocative efficiency and productive efficiency.

Allocative efficiency means that economic resources are being used in the production of goods and services that the public most desire, while productive efficiency refers to the fact that total output or service of a firm is achieved at the lowest possible cost for economic resources (this is sometimes referred to as X-efficiencies). Basic economics suggest that competition will result in both efficiencies gained.

However, the common agreement in the academic sector on such potential efficiency gains (for example, Estache, 2001) from privatising a public service such as public transport system rests fundamentally on the competition criteria. As evident, the profit incentive of commercial enterprises that spurs efficiency and productivity rests critically on the assumption of existing competition, or even the threat of potential competitors. Hence, this argument cannot be applied in Singapore’s context because there is no existing competition for the PTOs.

The World Is Not Enough
Mr. Lui also disagreed with some people who said that the PTOs should not be making so much profit, and that we should recognise that as public-listed companies, it is not unreasonable for the PTOs to earn fair returns from the sizeable capital investments required to sustain their operations and to invest in future public transport needs.

However, this is exactly what makes a privately-run PTO incentive incompatible with the social objective of providing good and affordable transport service to the public, especially when it operates in an environment without competition. In this case, it is difficult to determine what constitutes a fair return to the PTO. When the SMRT makes hundreds of millions in profits, pays its senior executive million-dollar salaries and still attempt to increase fares year after year (even in the year of the occurrence of the serious security lapse at the Changi depot), it is very difficult to justify to the public that SMRT practices corporate social responsibility.

Without competitive pressure, the incentive structure of a public listed company does not equate with the social objective of providing fundamental public services such as the transport system.

A Robust Framework To Regulate Bus And Rail Service?
Mr. Lui is right that it is important is to ensure that commuters’ interests are safeguarded when we have commercial enterprises running the public transport services. However, the key aspects highlighted by Mr. Lui that are being used to safeguard commuter’s interest are apparently not working well.

Firstly, let’s look at the performance record of the Public Transport Council (PTC) which has been set up to safeguard the interests of the commuters. The PTC fined SMRT a meagre sum of $100 for its service lapse in April 2010. Later in the year, the PTC was fined $50,000 (the maximum) for an extremely serious security lapse at the Changi depot but this was a paltry sum compared to the many human lives it could have cost.

In contrast, commuters could be fined $20 for non-payment or underpayment of correct fares and $50 for misuse of concession fares (PTC website).

The juxtaposition of these incidents seems to indicate that PTC tends to be more lenient towards the MRT than the general commuter. Put together with the fact that fare increases are being approved by the PTC year on year, it is difficult not to be suspicious over the claim that PTC is safeguarding public welfare.

Secondly, consider the formula used by the PTC (as revealed by Mr. Lui) to cap fare increments. If we look at the consumption weights of the CPI, transport spending contributes a significant proportion of the expenditure weights in the computation of CPI. In 2009, the transport expenditure is 16 percent, which is the third largest item in the basket of goods in CPI and shares the same spot with “recreation and others”. What this means is that fare increases are justified on the basis of previous fare increases!

In addition, the share of transport cost in CPI (16%) is not insignificant. Retaining transport cost in the CPI, and using that in the adjustment formula, will thus contribute to an upward spiral of fare increment. The use of the average national wage increment is even less desirable, since the number could simply increase to large increase in very high-income earners (such as banking executives, lawyers, doctors, etc). The average national wage is in fact a very poor indicator of the true earnings of average Singapore people, given the high income inequality as measured by the Gini coefficient (according to the Singapore department of Statistics, the Gini coefficient based on Original Income from Work per Household Member is 0.481 in 2008, 0.478 in 2009, and 0.480 in 2010).

Conclusion
Given the recent dismal performance of the PTOs, their attempt to apply for a transport fare increment is a signal of a monopolistic transport system in Singapore which is driven by the relentless quest for higher profits. All the various awards given to the SMRT or Transport Ministry is meaningless if it fails to reflect the true sentiments of the commuters.

Hence, the Transport Ministry should seriously discuss the possibilities of nationalising the PTOs plan offered by the Workers’ Party. Being aware of the downside of regulations or de-privatization, the PAP government should work together with the Worker’s party in designing a nationalization plan that can balance the social objective and the long-term sustainable operation of the PTOs.

Instead of totally abolishing the current system, the transport ministry could also consider reforming the current PTC system. Instead of having a council full of wealthy directors and highly-paid academicians, the PTCs should include at least 50 percent of its council members from alternative parties, who can better represent the voices of the average income-earners in Singapore who are main users of public transport.

As the Singapore government has always prided itself as a unique government in the world, I believe that Singapore can be the first successful example of de-privatization.


References:
Asiaone (2010) “SMRT fined $100 for service Lapse.” Asiaone April 05, 2010 issue.Baer, W., and Montes-Rojas, G. (2008) “From Privatization to Re-nationalization: What went Wrong with Privatizations in Argentina?” Oxford Development Studies, 36, pp. 323-337.

Chia, A.M. (2010) “Household Income in 2009 lower than in 2008 but still higher than in earlier years.” Singapore Department of Statistics Press Release.

Estache, A. (2001), “Privatization and Regulation of Transport Infrastructure in the 1990s.” The World Bank Research Observer, Vol 16, Number 1, pp. 85-108.

Lui, T.Y. (2011) “Nationalised Transport won’t run well.” Asiaone July 14, 2011 issue.

Megginson, W. L., and Netter, J.M. (2001) “From State to Market: A Survey of Empirical Studies on Privatization.” Journal of Economic Literature, 39, pp. 321-389.

Public Transport Council (PTC) website: http://www.ptc.gov.sg/regulation/penaltyFeeRegulation.htm

Savas, E. S. (2005) Privatization in the City: Successes, Failures, Lessons. Washington, DC: CQ Press, 2005

Singapore Department of Statistics (2009) “Singapore Consumer Price Index.” Singapore Department of Statistics Press Release.

SMRT Annual Reports. Source: http://www.smrt.com.sg/investors/annual_reports.asp

Wallsten, S. J. (2003) “An Econometric Analysis of Telecommunications Competition, Privatization, and Regulation in Africa and Latin America,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 49, pp. 1-19.

Subscribe
Notify of
0 Comments
Inline Feedbacks
View all comments
You May Also Like

阻断措施实施以来 警至少接476宗家暴投报

自阻断措施实施以来,家庭暴力也随之上升,促使当局必须积极主动采取行动协助这些高风险的家庭。 根据警方的数据显示,已接获至少476宗涉及家庭暴力相关犯罪的通报。比起阻断措施前每月平均389宗 ,增幅至少22巴仙。 其中包括以武力殴打、恐吓和非法监禁所造成的伤害。 对此,警方强调,他们对此严正以待,并加强与机构的合作。他们将会再次评估更多高风险家庭,即使受害者不准备寻求帮助,他们也会将其家庭转接到社会服务机构,确保他们能够获得更多帮助。 “警方会在评估时考量多方因素,包括加害者的个人信息与施加暴力的潜质“,警方表示。 而向当局寻求协助的受害者也将会被转介至社会与家庭发展部所资助的庇护所。与此同时,警方也会定期与受害者联系,评估受害者的情况,并查明他们是否需要更多的协助。 另一方面,为了能够将家庭暴力连根拔起,警方也会介入协助解决加害者对家庭成员施暴的原因。除了安排社工的介入,也会评估是否需要接受心理辅导或经济协助。加害者也会被转介至适当的机构接受协助。 协助家庭施暴者是去年由勿洛警察局试行的内政团队社区援助与转介计划,并将推展至所有警署。 警方于上月23日表示,在阻断措施实施期间,个人与家庭可能会承受更多的压力,也导致暴力的产生。 因此,警方敦促若身陷家庭暴力的人,可以向社会与家庭发展部寻求协助,同时也鼓励家庭成员或公众能够提高警觉,一旦发现家庭暴力发生,即报警处理。

招聘拭子测试员薪资引争议 卫生部澄清该工作属短期合约

为了能够应付大量的检测工作,政府欲招募数以千计的拭子检测人员和助理。然而,此举却引发部分医护人员的不满,有护士在网络上发文,直指拥有专业背景的护士薪资,竟不如非专业的拭子检测人员。 据该护士称,应届毕业的护士平均薪资约1千900元左右,甚至在工作了五至六年后都不一定达到3千800元月薪,然而未有任何的医疗专业背景下,竟然可以在短时间内获得3千800元的薪资。 对此,卫生部于今日(15日)回复媒体询问,拭子检测工作属于短期合约,与全职医护专业人士不同,并没有任何升迁的机会,也不会给予额外的补贴或花红。 而至于大量聘请测试员是为了要应付大规模的病毒检测工作。 卫生部亦表示,本地注册护士入行时,其月薪加上补贴和花红,也会在3300元至5200元,而且他们每年都会加薪,并有培训机构让他们可以发展成为临床护师(Nurse Clinician)、教育者或领导者。

Singaporean motorcyclist ‘Red Baron’ dies in tragic accident during Thailand journey: motorcycling community mourns loss

Singaporean motorcyclist Mohamed Reza Abdul Rashid, known as ‘Red Baron,’ tragically passed away in a Thai hospital after an accident. Mr. Reza was on a journey to central Thailand when the tragedy occurred. The motorcycling community mourned his loss, including the Ducati Motor Club Singapore. Reza’s wife, Huda Lajam, confirmed his passing on Facebook, expressing her deep love for him and their shared adventures. 📰 Follow TOC’s stories on Telegram: https://t.me/theonlinecitizenasia 📡