Gordon Lee/

In Part 2, we study costs of production, inflation, productivity and competitiveness.

Costs of production

A minimum wage policy will lead to increased costs for firms – but the degree to which costs increase is diluted by non-wage costs and higher wage earners.

Take a hypothetical firm, where 60% of total costs are labour costs. Even though 50% of its employees are low paid employees whose wages ($5/hr) will be increased with a minimum wage policy by 20% (to $6/hr), because they are lowly paid compared to managers and executives, they only constitute a third of the firm’s labour costs.

Even in this hypothetical firm with high labour costs as a proportion of total costs, a 20% increase in low wages increases the firm’s total costs by just 6% (60% x 50% x 20%).

Inflation

Even if we assume that every single firm in the economy is like our earlier example, with high labour costs and a high proportion of low paid employees, such that total costs of production in the entire economy increases by 6%, what will be the impact on inflation? The answer is that a 6% rise in total costs will lead to inflation (price rises) of less than 6%.

This is because firms respond to a rise in costs in a few ways; for example, by increasing productivity, saving costs by reducing working hours*, accepting lower profits, etc. – passing costs on to consumers is only one such way. No firm has the ability to pass on 100% of cost increases to consumers as price increases.

*According to the International Labour Organisation, Singapore has the longest working hours in the world.

Graphically, a rise in the costs of production by firms (upward shift of the aggregate supply curve from AS1 to AS2 by the distance between ‘a’ and ‘b’) leads to a rise in price from P1 to P2, instead of P1 to P3. This is because of the slope of the aggregate demand curve (AD).

It is also interesting to note that in the long run, the aggregate supply curve (ASLR) is vertical, so an increase in costs will not itself lead to any price rises (i.e. no inflation).

But even if there is inflation, is inflation bad?

1. A stable and modest inflation rate is generally healthy – but inflation that is too high or too low is not. For example, the Bank of England is tasked to target inflation at 2% (±1%).

2. It is said that inflation erodes savings, but it is because of this effect that consumer spending is encouraged (which has a stimulating effect on economic growth).
3. It is said that inflation reduces competitiveness by making domestic products more expensive to export, but changes in exchange rates reflect changes in prices – with the end result being that inflation has little, if any, effect on the real price of exports (which is what customers overseas are concerned with).
4. It is said that inflation penalises the poor more than the rich. Whilst that is generally true, in this case, we are talking about a wage increase for low wage earners because of a minimum wage. In other words, building on our examples, even though prices of goods may increase (through inflation) by, say. 2% for everyone, a minimum wage would increase hourly wages by 20% for low wage earners.

The effect of inflation in this case is like a redistributive tax which taxes everyone by 2% (small compared to our other taxes), but which helps the lowest paid in the country. Redistributive taxes are not new (high-income earners pay more in income tax than low-income earners). The difference is that a minimum wage really helps the lowest paid in society, and can even have a stimulating effect on economic growth as the poor spend more as a percentage of their income than the rich. In other words, give a rich person $10 and he invests most of it and only spends $1 in the economy, but give a poor person $10 and he would save $1 but spend $9 in the economy. So redistributive taxes, besides having a social aspect of helping the poor and increasing social cohesion, also generate wider economic benefits for everyone.

Productivity

According to the above UBS Prices and Earnings survey [1], Singapore’s hourly wages (productivity) is 30% that of New York’s. This is because Singapore’s growth has thus far relied mainly on foreign workers – the influx of which suppresses wages and productivity. [2] Firms have little incentive to increase productivity if they are able to rely on cheap labour. A national minimum wage policy allows low paid Singaporeans to compete with foreign labour not on price, but on skills – and also provide the incentive for firms to invest in increasing productivity.

In other words, the number of Singaporean workers employed in the economy as a whole should increase against that of foreign workers. The economic case is to reduce the negative effects associated with a large foreign workforce – as evidenced from Singaporeans’ concerns over effects such as rises in house prices and congestion on public transport. Notes Associate Professor Hui Wen Tat at the LKY School of Public Policy, “a large foreign worker population generates significant negative externalities”.[2]

He also says, “A minimum wage law would also have the salutary effect of making employers more efficient in using their workers. It would encourage them to hire better-quality workers with the requisite skills or those who can be trained to acquire such skills, so as to justify the higher wages. Employers will thereby be compelled to boost productivity, move up the value chain, thus increasing the demand for higher-paid jobs.” [2]

The government already intervenes in the market by setting foreign worker levies, imposing foreign worker quotas and specifying minimum salaries for S-Pass and Employment Pass holders. But that does not directly affect the wages of low-wage Singaporeans. It might be simpler, more efficient and effective for the government to set a minimum wage (to replace its current policies) for local and foreign workers – and allow the market to work freely from there.

Competitiveness

1. As mentioned, price rises (which affect competitiveness) are less than the rise in costs. Consumers only care about the prices of goods that they pay for, not about the costs to firms.

2. Please see point (3) above under the section ‘Inflation’ for mitigatory effects of exchange rates on competitiveness.

3. Any productivity increases will also help to cushion the rise in prices.
4. What is probably more important for sustainable long term economic growth is that a minimum wage will help to shift the competitiveness of Singapore firms from price competition to competition based on innovation, ideas and quality products. So rather than understanding the issue as a reduction in the level of competitiveness, we should understand it as a shift in the nature of competition.

Conclusion

In practice, it is necessary to start off with a modest minimum wage. When the UK first introduced a minimum wage, it was at an initial level of £3.60, which increased wage bills across the economy by about 0.5% (although different sectors were affected differently), and costs of production by less than 0.5%. [3]

I hope I have shown that there are many extenuating factors that reduce the ills of a minimum wage. These ills must also be weighed against the benefits of a minimum wage – for e.g. productivity growth, economic stimulus, balancing of local-foreign worker composition in the workforce. We will look at more benefits in the next instalment, which will also examine Workfare.

[1] http://www.ubs.com/2/e/medlib/wmr/pdf/Preise_Loehne_2010_e.pdf
[2] http://newasiarepublic.com/?p=20567 (This is a highly recommended article.)

[3] http://www.dti.gov.uk/files/file37987.pdf (pg. 6)

To read Part 1 of this debate, click here.

 

Subscribe
Notify of
0 Comments
Inline Feedbacks
View all comments
You May Also Like

四客工追讨工资网络疯传

劳资纠纷?据网民分享照片,四名客工站在联明建筑公司某建筑工地,手上拿着“我要工钱”标语,疑向该公司追讨工资。 有关消息也在社交媒体和Whatsapp疯传,另一视频则显示上述四名客工,站在一群工友前,手持标语。 此事引来民众为工友抱不平,也纷纷想了解工友抗议的建筑工地地点。网民Ah Seng感叹,通常可以帮助捍卫客工权益的资源有限,可能最终结果只能领回基薪并被遣返,但往往涉及压榨员工者不会被严厉对付。 他认为在国际上新加坡雇主对待客工的声誉很差,过去的案例就有不发工资、诈欺或者透过招工代理征收大笔中介费。此次个案或许只是冰山一角。 有网民称,联明曾负责承建许多政府工程。联明是本地一家上市建筑公司,若浏览该公司官网,可发现他曾承负责建许多建屋发展局、裕廊集团和陆路交通机构的公共住宅和基础设施工程项目,当前承建的工程包括建屋发展局在淡滨尼的149户组屋。 本社针对此流传视频,联系联明公司核实详情是否属实,目前仍待该公司回覆。

WP expresses concern about manner of investigations over alleged violations of “Cooling Off Day” regulations

The Workers’ Party issued a statement on Wednesday to express its concern…

狮城客工也有梦!为家乡设立专科学院,望能助下一代脱贫

客工也有梦!《亚洲新闻台》日前报导一名孟加拉籍客工的故事,身为建筑工地上的工人,辛苦累人的工作并没有磨灭他对梦想的追求,离乡背井到新加坡打工反而让他开拓眼界,决定在家乡打造属于自己的梦想。 当新加坡人对于上学学习习以为常时,乔伊·苏迪普·巴德罗(译名,Joy Sudip Bhadro )却对学习非常有兴趣,他常凝视学校门口外进进出出的学生。对他而言,这是全新的世界,而他只能望而却步。他因为经济因素限制,连中学课程都无法完成,无法以大学生的身份进入各大学院学习。 24岁时,他必须前往新加坡工作,赚取微薄的600新元负担家庭开销,他表示,他家族内共有11人,家庭开销庞大,“我只是一个什么都没有的穷小子。” 在工作期间,他偶然认识了来自汶莱的工人正在进行学位证书,而且因为学位证书而获得在办公室工作的机会,但因他的学历限制,他只能低就在工地工作,而他知道他并不是唯一一个。他了解在他的家乡,有非常多与他类似的青少年,仅完成了小学学历,被迫出来接受低薪、劳工和技术性工作。因此,他开始规划在家乡开设专科学校。 看见教育的力量,欲协助家乡孩子脱贫 现已42岁的乔伊已建立一所“东北部理想技术专科学院”(North East Ideal Polytechnic Institute),内有200名学生,是当地唯一一所职业学院。…

PSP’s Jeffrey Khoo urges Singaporeans to report unfair hiring; offers suggestions to curb this issue

The member of Progress Singapore Party (PSP) Jeffrey Khoo took to Facebook…