Gordon Lee /

Since the parliamentary “debate” in January this year, which saw Members of Parliament coming out strongly as a united front against implementing a minimum wage, discussions on the pros and cons of a minimum wage seem to have died down.

Government rhetoric asserts that a minimum wage policy has few merits, but significant demerits – such as unemployment, inflation and loss of competitiveness. Lee Hsien Loong was reported to have said, “Singapore has something better than a minimum wage and it is called Workfare.”

This multi-part series will examine these claims from two perspectives: economic theory, and empirical research. In this first instalment, we look at the alleged “unemployment” that is predicted to occur with a minimum wage.

Unemployment in theory

This simple textbook model is easily recognisable by A-Level economics students. Briefly, the downward-sloping demand curve shows that as wages fall along the Y-axis, firms’ demand for workers will increase rightwards along the X-axis. The upward-sloping supply curve shows that as wages increase along the Y-axis, more workers are willing to work for longer, and the supply of labour increases rightwards along the X-axis. The equilibrium level of employment in this perfectly competitive labour market is at E2, with the equilibrium wage at W1.

With a minimum wage set above the equilibrium wage (W1) at the level W min, workers are willing to supply E1 amount of labour, but firms are only willing to employ E3 amount of labour, leading to a fall in employment from E2 to E3 with unemployment as shown. So far, this is what ministers seem to be implying.

There is a problem with this theoretical understanding, as it is based on the assumption that firms operate in a perfectly competitive labour market with practically no ability to set wages. For example, fast food chains and supermarkets seem to have considerable power to determine wages, and the sector can be said to be closer to a monopsony (sole buyer with full control over wages) than a perfectly competitive market (infinite buyers each of small size with no control over wages).

 

Modelling the monopsonistic market is a little more complex. Although the equilibrium in the free market between Supply (S) and Demand (MRP) for labour is at point C, the monopsonist would choose to employ where his marginal cost (MC) is equal to his marginal benefit (MRP) at point A, hence employing L amount of labour instead of L’ in order to maximise profits. Since a monopsonist has the power to decide wages, he will pay the minimum amount (W) required to secure L amount of labour instead of the equivalent W’ under a perfectly competitive market.

There is also a deadweight welfare loss to society shown by the triangle ACM – which means that because resources are not efficiently allocated, the overall cost to society (in terms of both consumer and producer) is more than the overall benefit to society.

But, if a minimum wage is set at W’, than the monopsonist has no choice but to pay W’ instead of W level of wages, and in order to continue to maximise profits, the monopsonist will increase employment from L to L’. Not only is employment increased, but the deadweight welfare loss is also eliminated with a minimum wage. It’s highly counter-intuitive, but true. In some markets (which are closer to a monopsony rather than a perfectly competitive one), employment increases!

The Singapore economy is a complex one which the first textbook model cannot represent adequately. The economy comprises a mix of competitive and monopsonist markets, and though employment might decrease in more competitive markets, employment increases in more monopsonist markets, mitigating (though not necessarily eliminating) effects of employment/unemployment either way.

Unemployment in practice

“We find that minimum wages … do not have a negative impact on employment.” [1]

“To sum up, the evidence for the UK presented in this paper indicates that the effect of the introduction of the minimum wage on the probability of employment is insignificantly different from zero for all four demographic groups and in all three datasets used.” [2] (If you are interested in studying the empirical evidence further, reference [2] provides a great overview of research done so far (US, UK, France), and the results.)

Due to the mitigating effects of monopsonist markets, it is no wonder that most empirical studies show little significant overall impact of a minimum wage on employment.

In any case, as past recessions have shown (and the government is quick to point out), any rise in unemployment is partially absorbed by foreign workers. The remaining unemployment has to be weighed against the benefits of a minimum wage, which will be explored in subsequent articles.

Conclusion

While a staggeringly high minimum wage could decrease overall employment, economic theory and empirical statistics demonstrate that a minimum wage set at a modest level* has little (if any) negative effect on unemployment. Unemployment should also be weighed against achieving a country’s other economic and social objectives.

*See http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/1560/1/WRAP_Stewart_twerp630.pdf (pg. 29) for an elaboration

In subsequent parts of this series, I aim to show that there are strong economic as well as social justifications for the implementation of a national minimum wage.

————-

References;

[1] The Effects of Minimum Wages on Employment: Theory and Evidence from Britain

[2] The Impact of the Introduction of the UK Minimum Wage on the Employment Probabilities of Low Wage Workers

 

Subscribe
Notify of
0 Comments
Inline Feedbacks
View all comments
You May Also Like

New Naratif’s Kirsten Han wins Human Rights Press Awards 2019 for article on fake news bill

Editor-in-chief of Southeast Asian affairs platform New Naratif Kirsten Han has won…

未出征先遭港网民起底 大陆网军“帝吧”解散

大陆网军“帝吧”原本计划“出征香港”,到港社交媒体平台洗版,殊不知遭香港网民先发制人,搜出和公开帝吧管理员个资,结果“出师未捷”,群组不得不解散。 连日来港反“逃犯条例”风波延续,而中国“帝吧”群组以声援香港警察和特区政府为名,要到香港社交平台“连登”、“民间人权阵线”脸书专页等响应反逃犯条例的平台洗版。 “帝吧”原名“李毅吧”,是百度贴的论坛版块,原本是在2004年为嘲讽李毅而设,攻击模式并不是技术性的黑客攻击,而是“人海战术”,号召大量网民洗版迅速留言发帖,即便其微博群组也打着“帝吧出征,寸草不生”的旗号。 个资保护薄弱  高考分数都搜得到 帝吧扬言要在7月23日攻击连登,殊不知其主要管理员的身份迅速被起底。由于中国采网络实名制,个资关联性很高且保护薄弱,被暴露的信息非常多,包括真名、身份证号码、住家地址、照片、手机号,甚至连银行余额、支付宝记录,就连高考分数都找得到。 甚至有人代其中一名管理员报名参军,在宗教栏填写“伊斯兰教”,标明优先加入“艰苦地区部队”。 最终,“帝吧”团长尹垣程则以“不破坏香港民众正常生活秩序”为名,宣告出征连登活动落幕;至于帝吧官微公开“帝吧”解散,但强调解散不是人数,而是群组被渗透得太厉害,信息过多连微博都开不了,解散后再组另一个五千人的群组。 过去,帝吧曾攻击被指“台独”的台湾艺人周子瑜,迫使后者录视频道歉;2018年,大陆游客声称在瑞典遭不公待遇,帝吧也翻墙洗版瑞典外交部,以及攻击被指“辱华”的名牌Dolce&Gabbana。 曝露中国个资管理不足问题 而网军出师不利,个资先被起底,也显示中国个资保护的隐忧,甚至只要花钱就能获得详细的个资。

Were the 27 arrested Bangladeshis terrorists?

By Teo Soh Lung When news of the arrest of 27 Bangladeshis…